Innovation - it's economics all the way down

Produced by DALL-E

One of the most enduring myths of innovation is that of the inspired genius. “Eureka!” (I’ve found it) exclaimed Archimedes as he ran, naked and dripping wet, around the streets of Syracuse. Da Vinci would have been unimpressed by the display. “Where there is shouting, there is no true knowledge,” he’d probably mutter into his beard, trying to get back into The Zone while doodling his designs for the helicopter. On a rooftop nearby, Tim Berners-Lee is being struck by his HTTP lightning flash, single-handedly ushering in the Digital Age.

This is not how innovation happens. Innovation occurs in the dizzying interplay of forces across all levels of society. I’m not an economist but the longer I work in innovation, the more I believe that it’s economics all the way down. While the socio-economic landscape of innovation is complex, there appears to be a Golden Thread we can use to increase clarity and effectiveness.

What is an economy?

An economy is a system of interaction or exchange. A simple model describes an economy as being composed of five levels. I prefer to think of these levels as layers of an onion, or gobstopper, the outer containing the inner.

From the outermost layer to the centre these are:

  • International
  • Government
  • Business
  • Household
  • Individual

Each layer contains agents that make decisions or choices. In the International layer, an agent might be a nation-state, perhaps. In the Government layer, it might be a specific department, agency or district. In the Business layer, agents might be commercial or not-for-profit organisations, industrial bodies, or perhaps groups inside an organisation such as the board or the IT department. In the Household layer agents are groups of people living together.

Individuals are, well, you and me. Behavioural Economics has a lot to say about the decision-making, conscious or unconscious, conducted in this layer. Economics of one sort or another, all the way down.

So, if an economy is a system of interaction or exchange, across multiple layers of society, each populated with decision-making agents, then it is these decisions that are the critical actions causing innovation, or stagnation.

The interplay of micro and macro

The decisions of individual agents at a micro-level influence the pattern of the macroeconomy. Much like the complexity seen in a murmuration of starlings: the flocking behaviour appears both random and somehow choreographed. It is a function of the interaction of agents (starlings) who each follow simple rules. Simple decisions made by each individual starling combine to generate complex behaviour at the more macro organisational layer. Individual decisions, conscious or unconscious, and the behaviours that subsequently flow from them, influence the pattern of the whole organisation.

This complexity from simple rules may be studied in the abstract in John Conway’s Game of Life. This mathematical model relies on the notion of cellular automata — cells on a flat, infinite, spreadsheet-like grid that are programmed with simple rules relating to when cells should live, die or be born. For example:

  • A dead cell with exactly three live neighbours becomes a live cell (birth)
  • A live cell with two or three live neighbours stays alive (survival)
  • In all other cases, a cell dies or remains dead (overcrowding or loneliness)

Then a set of cells are turned on by the “controller” to act as a seed state. The model is then activated, stepping through a generation every second or so. Much like the murmuration of starlings, the Game of Life produces complex patterns from simple rules.

Sometimes these patterns, subject to the initial placement of seed cells, achieve a sort of life of their own. Patterns travel across the grid. Sometimes a type of flocking behaviour is exhibited. Other times parts of a pattern may be seen breaking off to join with other escapees to create new patterns of their own together.

Conway's Game of Life Conway’s Game of Life

In this admittedly simplistic model, the grid represents the macro, outer layers of the economy. The cells, agents or starlings representing the micro inner layers. The rules represent the decision-making of agents in any layer. The relationship between the structure, rules and seeds is critical in determining whether patterns will flourish or die off.

When it comes to innovation in this sort of economic model, the relationship between the macro/outer and micro/inner layers is critical. States and businesses are social organisms. A lone starling, regardless of its genius, can’t hope to influence the macro pattern.

Innovation Economics

When it comes to innovation in the real economy, the State has an important role. As one of the outermost layers, it contains many others within it.

The State has a history of taking on risks associated with unproven, technological innovation: aviation, nuclear energy, computers, the internet, GPS, nano and biotechnology amongst others. While conducting her research, economist Mariana Mazzucato discovered “The more I looked (into the economics of innovation), the more I realised: state investment is everywhere”. There is a strong precedent for an ongoing innovation relationship between the state and agents in other layers of the economy.

While not a new concept, innovation economics espouses exactly this sort of relationship. Joseph Schumpeter introduced the notion of an innovation economy in his 1942 book “Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy”. In contrast to his contemporary John Maynard Keynes, Joseph Schumpeter contended that evolving institutions, entrepreneurs and technological change were at the heart of economic growth, not independent forces that are largely unaffected by policy. This perspective seems particularly apt given state investment in innovation since the publication of his book.

A Golden Thread

Innovation by agents across various layers of the economy, from the international to the individual, appears dauntingly complex. So, how might we practically approach it?

In our experience with a wide range of organisations, there seems to be a factor common to the most successful innovation initiatives. Much like Conway’s Game of Life, or the murmuration of starlings, it turns out to be a simple “golden thread” that links the layers of the economy: shared priorities.

Shared priorities create clarity for all concerned with innovation, within and between teams, whether representing departments, businesses or the more macroeconomic layers. With shared priorities, participants reach greater levels of effectiveness and true partnerships are allowed to form. With shared priorities, the purpose of innovation becomes more evident — something that it’s easy to lose sight of. Shared priorities allow participants to have a reasonable discussion about the best next step, minimising the subjectivity that often derails an initiative.

While beyond the scope of this article, systems for translating shared priorities between the layers of the economy, like our current version of capitalism, might be said to be performing poorly. Even DAVOS are promoting the need for a new kind of capitalism.

What does seem to work well, however, in achieving shared priorities, is a systematic approach to group decision-making. Daniel Kahneman, Nobel Laureate for Economics and “grandfather” of behavioural economics, has found that groups tend to make better decisions when supported by algorithms.

“Algorithms beat individuals about half the time. And they match individuals about half time,” Kahneman says. “There are very few examples of people outperforming algorithms in making predictive judgments. So, when there’s the possibility of using an algorithm, people should use it. We have the idea that it is very complicated to design an algorithm. An algorithm is a rule. You can just construct rules.”

One of the benefits of an algorithmic, systematic approach to group decision-making is that it can make it clear to participants what their shared priorities really are. It will make it equally clear where priorities aren’t shared too, which is often just as valuable in avoiding over-commitment to a particular course of action. Algorithmic systems can reduce subjectivity, bias and the “noise” associated with deciding what to do next.

A general health warning though: with algorithms as with most systems, it’s garbage in, garbage out. A repeatable system is only as good as the quality of the inputs.

Summary

Innovation occurs across all layers of the economy, from the international to the interpersonal, and is rarely achieved by a lone genius. The complexity of innovating in this environment can be daunting. The golden thread of shared priorities can increase innovation effectiveness between these layers. Systematic and/or algorithmic approaches to group decision-making are effective at achieving such a set of shared priorities.

> END OF LINE
Innovation - it's economics all the way down
Older post

Decision models and trust

I’m interested in why decision models are important, now and in the unfolding future.

Newer post

What should you automate?

Automation operates on tasks, not entire jobs.

Innovation - it's economics all the way down